No business case for lots of wind and solar

In recent years, the increasing competitiveness of wind and solar power has been widely hailed. But there is a cloud to this silver lining – power production does not match power demand. As a result, the actual value of wind and solar power will decrease as we get more of it. Craig Morris says policymakers should pay attention.

Solar power and the grid

The more solar and wind power we have, the more important it becomes to match power demand.


While everyone celebrates the increasing competitiveness of wind and solar, German analyst Lion Hirth says the value of these energy sources to our energy supply will decrease as we build more.

Electricity Production in Germany in December 2014

On 1 December, 2014, Germany’s conventional power fleet was able to sell around 60 GW of electricity at nearly 7 cents per kilowatt-hour. But just before Christmas, wind power picked up, bringing conventional generation down to around 20 GW – and the price down to a single cent. Sales revenue thus dropped to 1/21th of its high level, from 420 (60 x 7) to 20 (20 x 1). Clearly, wind and solar cannot finance themselves on wholesale markets because prices will plummet as soon as a lot of wind or solar is available. Edited chart taken from Fraunhofer ISE.

First, we have to make a distinction between price and value. The price is what wind and solar power cost. The value is what that green electricity offsets. Solar campaigners in the US talk about the value of solar instead of the price because solar power production peaks at midday – at a time of peak consumption. This solar power therefore initially offsets peaking generators, which are more expensive to run.

But for how long? A few years ago, analysts at the Brattle Group found that enough PV to cover around seven percent of peak demand would actually save costs overall in Texas. But what happens when PV peaks at 15 or 20 percent of demand?

Hirth has looked into this matter repeatedly. His numbers apply for Germany and cannot be transferred, say, to Texas, which has air-conditioning – and hence higher power consumption in the summer than in the winter (the opposite of Germany). But the principle applies everywhere, and it does not look pretty for high penetration levels of wind and solar power.

Value Factor of Wind and Solar Power

Source: Lion Hirth

Both wind and solar power start off with a value exceeding the price; the “value factor” is above 1.00. “Wind power production correlates seasonally with power demand, at least in Germany, whereas solar power production correlates with daily power peaks around noon,” Hirth explains the value factor above 1.00. But the value of wind power falls below that level when it makes up only a few percent of total supply. Solar starts off with a much higher value but quickly plummets. Once the value factor has fallen below 1.00, the price of this electricity is greater than the power it offsets.

Hirth’s numbers represent the share of wind and solar in electricity supply, not the share of peak demand. Solar now covers around seven percent of total power demand in Germany but peaks at close to a third of demand quite regularly on sunny days. So the business case for wind and solar gets worse as penetration levels increase – even as the price of these energy sources becomes more competitive.

Here, we see the challenges from the utility perspective. This is how campaigners in the US depict the value of solar:

Value of solar vs. cost vs. residential electricity price

Source: ILSR

The value of solar remains constant (in Minnesota) rather than dropping, according to Hirth’s calculation. As the article for the chart explains, the perspective is the consumer’s, not the utility’s. As a former Vattenfall (one of the main utilities in Germany) employee (but now independent), Hirth shows us that power markets will see a diminishing value for wind and solar. The “value of solar” argument therefore only works at very low levels of penetration from the utility perspective. At higher levels, it works against wind and solar.

For the past few years, there has been a growing recognition that, to quote German energy analyst David Jacobs, “refinancing any type of power plant via spot market sales of electricity will be increasingly difficult.” But conventional plants can respond to low prices by reducing production. As I put it once, wind and solar undercut themselves; the more wind and solar power is produced, the lower prices will be on wholesale markets.

Hirth estimates that there is practically no business case for more wind and solar in Germany at a combined penetration level of around 50 percent in Germany. Yet, the German government has an official target of 80 percent renewable electricity, and the large gap will not be filled by biomass, hydropower, and imports. Wind and solar will have to grow far beyond 50 percent.

I interpret Hirth’s analysis to show how useful feed-in tariffs will be towards meeting a political target that the market cannot bring about on its own. Hirth disagrees. “Numerous political recommendations can be drawn from my analysis,” he argues.

Wind and solar face an era of much slower growth in Europe. Spain and Italy reached high levels but have practically collapsed since, for instance. European governments are increasingly pushing for wind and solar to react to price signals. But because they undercut themselves, the only way these two energy sources can react to price signals is by not growing any further. Without policy changes, the market will not push the energy transition to 80 percent renewable power. Indeed, the transition might be over much earlier. After all, it was society that called for the Energiewende, not the market.

Craig Morris (@PPchef) is the lead author of German Energy Transition. He directs Petite Planète and writes every workday for Renewables International.

by

Craig Morris (@PPchef) is co-author of Energy Democracy, the first history of Germany’s Energiewende.

8 Comments

  1. Ivor O'Connor says

    You missed his qualifying word “practically”. Obviously Hirth has a political motive for misrepresenting the case. It doesn’t matter much. As more and more of society uses batteries for household energy storage and transportation we’ll soon need more than 200% of the electricity currently needed. Storage is a total game changer. Hirsh will look like the idiots who said only 10 computers in the world will ever be needed. T

  2. heinbloed says

    Price and value – what REs could offset isn’t what they do in the official balance sheets.
    Thanks to subsidies, socialized costs and price dumping. As Reuters reports from France:

    http://www.reuters.com/article/2015/07/17/france-electricity-idUSL5N0ZW1HK20150717

    Quoting the second and third last sentence:

    ” New entrants to an electricity market that EDF dominates find it hard to compete with prices that are artificially capped, but their legal challenges have so far failed.

    “By not increasing tariffs enough we have loaded a colossal backlog in today’s charges on to future generations,” said Fabien Chone, chairman of Anode, the association of alternative power providers. ”

    The situation is fully compareable with Germany, despite a “free market” there the costs of the old powers are not reflected by the prices they charge per kWh

    And a similar situation in Finland where Fortum just published their half years results:

    http://globenewswire.com/news-release/2015/07/17/752953/0/en/Interim-Report-January-June-2015-Low-electricity-prices-continued-to-impact-results-negatively-somewhat-compensated-by-hydro-volumes.html

    It looks hell for Fortum, but in public they hope for an increase in power demand in the Scandinavian countries of 0.5%/a …..

    That the power prices are falling much faster and the RE’s gaining market shares much quicker they just realized, they were safed by hydro power this year.

    In a different statement they lament of their lost money in atomic power plant upgrades in Sweden, majority co-owner EoN can’t see any future in them anymore:

    http://globenewswire.com/news-release/2015/06/23/746649/0/en/Fortum-would-prefer-continued-operations-at-Oskarshamn-nuclear-power-units-1-and-2.html?parent=752953

  3. heinbloed says

    Concerning the first chart (” Electricity production in Germany in December 2014″) the small generators are missing.
    Click an “All” in the ISE Fraunhofer data collection page, there in the left column.
    The picture looks better in full colour 🙂

  4. Mike D says

    The piece not shown here is the value factor for a nuclear, coal or gas plant. I suspect that their values also go down as they become a greater portion of the grid. We purposely overbuilt the coal, gas and nuclear, knowing that they would need to be curtailed at times of low demand. In a fossil free future we will also need to overbuild renewables, curtailing their output occasionally, lowering their ‘total’ and off-peak values.

    Unfortunately, the fuel costs for wind and solar are zero, so the marginal costs are nearly zero as well. This is not true for fossil fuels, and so they are being priced out of the market at times.

    There will be a need for some backup or storage. Hydro plays well here, and can expand in some places. The current buzz is batteries here, but it is not the cheapest. currently fossil fuel peakers fill in at a much higher price, sitting idle for most of the year. When storage costs come down further those technologies will replace the current generation of peakers as well.

  5. S. Herb says

    Thank you for the reference to the Hirth paper, this is just what Jesse Jenkins is referring to with capacity factor limits, and is certainly important for current policy design. On the other hand, it is looking at small changes away from the already highly optimized system. There are now several extensive simulations describing energy mixes for Germany in 2050, with very limited fossil fuel usage, 80% or more reduction in CO2 emissions, and typically 15-20% PV contribution to the entire energy economy (not just electricity). These have, in some cost optimized fashion, filled in the holes in the PV contribution. It would be useful to see what the value of solar looks like in these re-optimized scenarios. The Fraunhofer ISE German-2050 study, in particular, shows a very broad cost minimum for trading off between wind and solar.

  6. Hans says

    What is missing from the equation is the external costs of conventional power production. The reason most of us support renewables is because of the damage that conventional power production does to our health and climate. If you would take these damages into account the price of conventional power production will always be at least the fuel costs plus the external costs. This would create a totally different business case for renewables.

  7. […] On the other hand, the market value of wind and solar power continues to drop. This value represents the ratio of the price paid for the electricity relative to the spot market price at the time it is sold to the exchange. A value below 1 means that the electricity is of less value than the power on the exchange. In 2016, onshore wind had a market value of 0.873, compared to 0.827 this year. Offshore wind fell from 0.921 to 0.906. Likewise, solar power fell from 0.997 to 0.949. This decrease is inevitable; it is called the cannibalization effect. […]

  8. […] On the other hand, the market value of wind and solar power continues to drop. This value represents the ratio of the price paid for the electricity relative to the spot market price at the time it is sold to the exchange. A value below 1 means that the electricity is of less value than the power on the exchange. In 2016, onshore wind had a market value of 0.873, compared to 0.827 this year. Offshore wind fell from 0.921 to 0.906. Likewise, solar power fell from 0.997 to 0.949. This decrease is inevitable; it is called the cannibalization effect. […]

Leave a Reply to S. Herb Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *